by Ian Angus
In A left ‘exit strategy’ from fossil fuel capitalism? published in Climate & Capitalism last week, Norwegian socialist Anders Ekeland urges ecosocialists to support the climate change program proposed by one of the world’s most-respected climate scientists, James Hansen, in many essays and speeches and in his book, Storms of my Grandchildren. In support of his argument, Ekeland particularly cites John Bellamy Fosters’ article James Hansen and the climate-change exit strategy, published in Monthly Review in February 2013.
I entirely agree that Hansen’s proposals are an important contribution to building a global movement to reduce greenhouse gas emissions by radically reducing the use of fossil fuels, and I fully endorse Foster’s discussion of Hansen’s program. That’s why, contrary to Ekeland’s assertion that Climate & Capitalism has ignored the subject, we recommended Foster’s article to C&C readers just days after it was published. Indeed, months before that C&C published a short article by Hansen that argued for his fee and dividend plan. Obviously we could have done more, but Ekeland is simply wrong to say there has been “no discussion” of this in C&C.
It’s good to have more attention drawn to this important issue, but unfortunately Ekeland reduces Hansen’s program to just one element – fee and dividend – entirely omitting many essential components. He compounds that error by using fee and dividend as a starting point for defending carbon taxes in general.
These omissions and additions reflect a deep misunderstanding of Hansen’s program. If it were as limited as Ekeland’s article implies, it would have little relevance to ecosocialist organizing.
Fee and Dividend
Hansen calls his fee and dividend plan the “essential backbone” of his proposals for reducing greenhouse gas emissions. Under it, a substantial fee would be levied on all fossil fuels at the well head, mine shaft, or point of entry, and subsidies to the fossil fuel industry would be eliminated. The fee, which would increase in predictable steps over time, would be paid by fossil fuel companies, and each month every legal resident would receive an equal share of the money collected, as a direct bank deposit or debit card.
This would directly increase the price of fossil fuels as such, and indirectly increase prices for products and services that use fossil fuels, but Hansen calculates that the poorest 60% of the U.S population, who generally have small carbon footprints, would receive more in dividends than they would pay in increased fuel and other prices.
The plan would be more transparent and easier to administer than other proposed schemes. If done properly, it would create an economic incentive for both corporations and consumers to reduce their carbon footprints by increasing energy efficiency and switching to alternatives.
Although Ekeland argues that the left should adopt the fee and dividend plan as the basis of a “common strategic campaign to mobilize people for an exit from fossil fuel society,” he is peculiarly ambivalent about one of its central features, the 100% direct dividend distribution.
On one hand, he appears to accept Hansen’s case for a direct dividend: “‘Climate’ money each month going into poor people’s bank accounts would unite the demand for income redistribution with working people’s fundamental long-term environmental demand for a healthy planet.” But elsewhere he contradicts himself by describing the plan as “adapted to the U.S. political context” and “completely individualistic,” and suggesting that in other countries the money collected could be spent by government on social projects.
Such confusion is disturbing. Unlike every actual carbon tax plan proposed or implemented in the world today, Hansen’s fee and dividend plan has a strong class component: it would take from rich corporations and give to the poor, creating a material incentive for working people to support the carbon fee and oppose corporate efforts to weaken it. If the money goes into government projects, no matter how worthy, it will be seen as just another attack on working class living standards, and how it is spent will be subject to the whims of capitalist politicians.
Is that all there is?
Anyone who reads only Ekeland’s article would conclude that Hansen’s “exit strategy” is just fee and dividend, nothing more. The readers who have commented that the plan is insufficient are judging Ekeland’s presentation, not Hansen’s, because, contrary to the impression Ekeland creates, fee and dividend is only one aspect of Hansen’s exit strategy.
Other key measures in Hansen’s program include:
- Shutting down all coal-fired plants that lack carbon capture and storage capability. (That technology is not yet available.)
- Stopping all production of non-conventional fossil fuels, including tar sands oil, shale oil and gas, and methane hydrates.
- Active implementation of a wide range of carbon conservation policies.
- A global transition in farming and forestry practices to implement carbon retention in the soil and global reforestation.
- Development of so-called fourth-generation nuclear technology, with strict safety controls. (That technology is not yet available.)
- Reducing non-CO2 climate forcings such as methane, ozone and black carbon.
Hansen is very clear that stopping coal and unconventionals is the one measure without which all else will fail, but Ekeland doesn’t mention that or any of the other measures Hansen proposes.
As Foster says, the policies Hansen considers to be essential are shown not just by what he writes, but by his actions. “He has been arrested in an attempt to block coal-fired plants and in a protest over the Keystone XL pipeline designed to bring Alberta tar sands oil to the Gulf of Mexico. His activism, and willingness to be arrested in relation to these issues, shows what he considers to be essential. … A mere increase in the carbon price is insufficient where coal and unconventional fossil fuels are concerned, and actual bans are necessary.”
How does fee and dividend fit in? It’s evident from his books and articles that Hansen sees it as a framework for high-level negotiations. He writes, “the key requirement is that the United States and China agree to apply across-the-board fees to carbon-based fuels.” They would force others to follow suit by imposing import duties on products from countries that don’t levy a carbon fee.
Given that approach, it’s not surprising that Hansen’s fee and dividend advocacy mainly involves lobbying politicians and governments, rather than grassroots action. That’s why Foster, while recognizing its progressive features, says fee and dividend is “mostly a top-down, elite-based strategy.”
And that’s why fee and dividend can be part of a radical action program against climate change, but isn’t sufficient by itself, and isn’t suitable for building the mass movements that socialists know are needed.
All out for carbon taxes?
Ekeland believes that left’s lack of enthusiasm for Hansen’s plan reflects a “long tradition of quite correctly fighting against indirect, regressive and socially unjust taxes.” I agree: most of the leftish criticisms of Hansen that I’ve seen have failed to see the broad range of measures that Hansen advocates, and the important ways in which fee and dividend differs from most carbon tax plans.
But having said that the left has “quite correctly” opposed such taxes, Ekeland promptly reverses himself, calling opposition to tax-driven price increases “a fairly dogmatic tradition.” He strongly criticizes me, Simon Butler, Tim Anderson and Daniel Tanuro for pointing that in the real world – not some fantasy world where taxes are imposed by impartial governments for the common good – most plans to “put a price on carbon” hurt working people while boosting corporate profits.
Rather than discussing Hansen’s full program, Ekeland uses one of its proposals as a jumping-off point to argue that using taxes and markets to influence consumer behavior is the only practical and effective way to reduce emissions. Leftists who disagree display “a lack of understanding of markets as a social institution.” He points to the fact that sales of electric cars jumped in Norway when taxes on them were cut as proof that “when the prices and context change, behavior can change.” By implication, the emission problem is caused by consumer behavior, and fixing the market is the solution.
The alternative, which he calls “command-and-control regulation,” is not only “totally unrealistic” but would likely lead to “black markets for energy, with horrific prices and speculation.” No wonder he doesn’t mention that Hansen’s program features an outright ban on coal and unconventional fuel production!
This isn’t the place for a full discussion of the advantages and (mostly) disadvantages of trying to use markets to solve environmental problems. The key point is made clearly in Foster’s article: “All exclusively market-based strategies tend to backfire, since they rely principally on economic incentives. Hansen’s fee and dividend is necessary under present conditions but is only a single wedge in what must be a much more comprehensive climate-change exit strategy.”
Ekeland reduces Hansen’s program to a single wedge, and his contradictory comments about direct dividends reveal confusion about key aspects of that. It is very difficult to see how his approach can be considered consistent with James Hansen’s climate change exit strategy.
+ + + + + +
While I disagree with him on important issues, I greatly appreciate Anders Ekeland’s initiative in opening a discussion on climate change exit strategy. Only through open and frank debate of these issues can we develop the action program that ecosocialists and other radical green activists need. I look forward to a thoughtful discussion in the Comments section below, and I’m sure Climate & Capitalism will publish further articles on this subject.
Well, if as you and Foster say “fee and dividend is not and exit strategy” then why waste our time campaigning for something that can’t possibly work when there are plenty of other very good anti-fossil fuel struggles out there that can work?Stopping fracking for example, is possible, and it does reduce fossil fuel consumption. It’s also the sort of campaign that one can build real movements around because there is already many community and state-wide struggles against it. Same with anti-pipeline struggles. These sorts of struggles can be won and I think they offer many opportunities to raise anti-capitalist politics.
I don’t pretend to have any expertise about movement building. I know we have to work with people who hold all sorts of illusions about potential reforms within capitalism. I personally don’t have any problem working with them even though I make it clear that I think the carbon tax idea is a non-starter. More importantly, it seems to me that the carbon tax strategy has three disadvantages from the standpoint of movement building:
First, it’s not even tendentially anti-capitalist because it assumes that if you pass a meaningful carbon tax, this will meaningfully reduce fossil fuel consumption, without any need to change the system. So we just get the tax passed and go back to sleep.
Secondly, it steers people into lobbying campaigns instead of mass actions. And this is just a dead end, most obviously, because, as I explained in my paper, no capitalist government on earth is going to pass a carbon tax that would meaningfully suppress CO2 emissions because they all (correctly) understand that this would meaningfully suppress economic growth which is what every government, every company and every union in the world right now is pulling out all the stops to prevent.
Thirdly, I think there is virtually no chance of building any kind of mass movement around the idea of a carbon tax. Who is going to support raising a flat tax, a tax that falls most heavily on the workers who are most of the voters? And if that weren’t enough, why, given capitalism, would anyone want to impose a tax that is certain to hurt the economy?
For all these reasons, spending time and effort promoting carbon taxes seems to me a waste of time — and a diversion from other more fruitful struggles with more political potential. As I see it, the main reason people like Hansen and mainstream environmental groups support carbon taxes is because it’s not threatening, it’s not anti-capitalist, it fosters the illusion that we can really reduce emissions without having to overturn the social order. That has obvious attractions. But it doesn’t mean that carbon taxes would actually work to slow global warming, or that a carbon tax campaign would be a useful movement-building tool.
This is an important debate. I think labour and social movements should welcome James Hansen’s proposal, while bearing in mind that it is a proposal for Keynesian regulation and, as such, is part of an approach that has in my view been left behind by history. It’s welcome not because it’s “the answer”, but because Hansen is breaking out of just giving “policy advice” as scientists are usually limited to doing.
But surely the “human tipping point” that he calls for is going to be much, much more than a carbon tax … getting past the age of fossil fuels surely IS, in the big picture, about getting past capitalism. To my mind socialists should focus more on rethinking how that transition will take place and not get bogged down in details of policy demands; the transition is about social overturns that consist of much more than policies.
Without realising you had started this debate here, I wrote (and just posted today) a comment on the paper published by Hansen et al in PLOS: http://peopleandnature.wordpress.com/2014/05/15/climate-scientists-go-for-human-tipping-point/
Ian, you write:
“On one hand, he appears to accept Hansen’s case for a direct dividend: “‘Climate’ money each month going into poor people’s bank accounts would unite the demand for income redistribution with working people’s fundamental long-term environmental demand for a healthy planet.” But elsewhere he contradicts himself by describing the plan as “adapted to the U.S. political context” and “completely individualistic,” and suggesting that in other countries the money collected could be spent by government on social projects.
“Such confusion is disturbing. Unlike every actual carbon tax plan proposed or implemented in the world today, Hansen’s fee and dividend plan has a strong class component: it would take from rich corporations and give to the poor, creating a material incentive for working people to support the carbon fee and oppose corporate efforts to weaken it. If the money goes into government projects, no matter how worthy, it will be seen as just another attack on working class living standards, and how it is spent will be subject to the whims of capitalist politicians.”
Actually, up to this point I thought Ekeland’s suggestion that the revenue from the new fees be spent by governments on social programs was similar to what the Bolivian government does: assigning the revenue from the increased taxes and royalties imposed on the foreign oil and gas companies still operating under contract in the country to various social programs such as the conditional cash transfers to pensioners, mothers and expectant mothers of infants, public school students, etc.
How does a direct dividend to the poor, which can be spent at their discretion as consumers, offer a superior investment to social programs that are of immediate use in raising living standards and reducing income disparities? Surely we are dealing here with the question of government, and thinking in terms of what a progressive government, operating in the interests of working people, would do.
That’s why the question of taxation and fiscal revenues cannot be discussed in the abstract (as many leftists do), but must always be addressed to the programs to which such revenues are to be devoted. No to war spending, yes to progressive social programs, for example.
Richard
WHY HANSEN’S CARBON TAX AND DIVIDEND IS NOT AN EXIT STRATEGY FROM FOSSIL FUEL CAPITALISM
With all due respect to Anders Ekeland, in my critique of green capitalism article published three years ago in RWER and reposted on this website, I effectively demonstrated the hopelessly contradictory nature of Hansen’s proposal and showed why it is most certainly NOT an exit strategy from fossil fuel capitalism. This I showed is so because, most obviously, a carbon tax is not a cap. Fossil fuel executives like the CEO of ExxonMobil fully support carbon taxes because they understand that it’s not a cap, it’s just a line item, a cost of doing business, and one that can be passed on to consumers.
Tax or no tax, they project that global fossil fuel consumption will rise by 35% in 20 years, 65% in the developing world, and they are looking to produce it for the benefit of their shareholders. Whereas to stop global warming, what we need is not just a “cap” but an absolute suppression, a massive suppression of fossil fuel burning.
I said that Hansen was absolutely right that there can be no stopping global warming unless we bring a rapid halt to the extraction and burning fossil fuels. That, however, I argued, is all but inconceivable under capitalism given that not just electricity generation but manufacturing, transportation, industrial farming — virtually the entire economy — is based on fossil fuels. To suppress fossil fuel consumption by 90% would require that capitalist legislatures pass a carbon tax that would effectively shut down the biggest corporations in the world. This is just not going to happen.
To think otherwise, like Hansen does, is to live in a fantasy dreamworld. To “get off fossil fuels” we would need to massively retrench and entirely shut down vast swathes of current industrial production in the developed countries, effectively de-industrialize to an extent by shutting down all kinds of unnecessary, wasteful, and polluting fossil-fuel consuming industries — and this, I said, would require, as its prerequisite, the replacement of capitalism with a democratically-planned, publicly-owned ecosocialist economy.
To say that we would need a social revolution to stop global warming may not be what people want to hear, because that seems so implausible today, but I believe that this is the only conclusion that can be drawn from the science. This, I argued, does not at all mean that we should not fight for every possible reform in the meantime.
There are many good fights out there against fossil fuel consumption, fights against pipelines, against tar sands, against extreme extraction, and against the staggeringly wasteful consumption of fossil fuels everywhere, but the carbon tax “solution” is not a solution. It’s a delusion.
Readers may wish to look at my article here
Richard, I was very pleased to post your Green Capitalism article in Climate & Capitalism. I think you powerfully made your case that a carbon tax by itself would not make a significant difference to fossil fuel production or greenhouse gas emissions.
You are absolutely right that fee and dividend is not an exit strategy. That’s the point I made in my article, and John Bellamy Foster made in his, and, for that matter, it’s what Hansen says. The mistake Eveland makes is treating fee and dividend as the whole thing, rather than just one part.
The issue in this discussion is NOT whether a bureaucratically-imposed, administered-from-the-top tax would shake up big oil, but whether a program that includes fee-and-dividend alongside other key elements, such as an activist, on-the-ground fight to shut down coal and unconventionals – should be a part of what Foster calls a “climate change exit strategy” that contributes to mobilizing a mass climate change movement.
As we work to build that movement, we will find ourselves working alongside people who think that “putting a price on carbon” is the way to go. (If we don’t find ourselves working with them, we haven’t reached out enough.) Do we simply reject that and push them away? Or do we say, “yes, but it must have a clear class-based character that protects the living standards of working people and the poor” and raise Hansen’s proposal?
We need a program for mobilization, for action against climate change, that can win support from a broad range of current and potential activists. Hansen’s program isn’t sufficient, but I can’t think of a better one proposed by any other environmentalist with anything like his prominence and influence.
There is no reason to think that the fee and dividend plan conflicts with building a mass movement, unless it were seen as the sole solution, which would be patently absurd. Indeed, it offers us a principled basis for building a broad anti-climate-change movement, and beginning points for advancing a systemic challenge to capitalism.